-A A +A

Suggestions that carbon pricing is not working because Canada’s emissions have kept rising miss the mark, as a large chunk of the increase is due to rapid population growth. The country’s energy efficiency has, in fact, improved considerably under the carbon tax introduced by the federal government.

But unfortunately for carbon price supporters, Ottawa has directly contradicted the principle underlying the tax. In late October, it decided to selectively pause its application to heating oil, a fuel used primarily in homes in Atlantic Canada, ostensibly on affordability grounds, but largely viewed as a cynically political move. Quite logically, provincial leaders immediately asked for exemptions covering fuels used in their regions, such as natural gas.

By undercutting the principle of treating each unit of emissions equally, no matter the source, the federal government may have fatally wounded its own carbon tax legitimacy. The proposed oil and gas sector emissions cap further damages the equality principle. It has also confirmed the worst fears of investors relying on long-term carbon price signals to invest in emissions-reducing technology such as carbon capture.

The federal government should reconsider its approach, and find the right tool for the right job while minimizing confusing and contradictory policies – especially in light of a report from the Office of the Auditor General of Canada indicating that Ottawa is not on track to meet its targets.

Fixing the quantity of emissions rather than price is an option. The Quebec system works that way by capping total emissions and then trading the right to emit in a market-based system.

There are other types of strategies to reduce emissions, most of which Canada uses already. A recent working paper by respected economists Olivier Blanchard, Christian Gollier and Nobel prize winner Jean Tirole outlines the portfolio of policies to consider. Carbon pricing remains a big one; others include research and development (R&D), standards, bans and targeted subsidies. But they have to be done well and thoughtfully.

First, Ottawa can support low-emission technology. The C.D. Howe Institute has found that research support is best directed to emerging technologies not yet cost-competitive, rather than crowding out commercially-oriented research by private companies. Supporting Canadian companies to gain access to foreign markets is another way to help.

To avoid wasting taxpayer money, a government-funded R&D agency needs excellent governance: It should be independent and led by experienced science hands, subject grants to a rigorous peer-review process, select goals but not solutions in advance, publish results afterward and contain provisions to stop funding projects no longer working.

“Command-and-control” regulations such as bans and standards can also work. Regulations need to be realistically achievable. They work better when emissions are hard to measure at the firm or consumer level, when standardization is important for efficiency and competition, or when it’s hard for consumers to calculate the costs and benefits of taking action (such as installing a heat pump to heat your home in an environment with variable gas and electricity prices, and uncertain contractor quality). But they aren’t always appropriate: Canada’s zero-emission vehicle mandate is off-track, especially for light trucks.

Cost per reduced tonne has to remain at the forefront of any action. A subsidy, say for an electric vehicle, can be used, but it’s often a very expensive way to reduce emissions. It also need to be paid for, and that means it’s a tax. Subsidies tend to work best in situations where individual investors don’t capture the full benefit of their investment but where the aggregate benefits are great (for example, a network of EV charging stations).

For all policies, Ottawa needs to know what is working and what is not. A monitoring unit tracking outcomes and rapidly sharing outcomes would help.

The federal government gravely damaged its credibility on existing carbon tax. It’s time for it to carefully re-evaluate its carbon pricing policy and the remaining patchwork of policies, eliminate those that aren’t working and figure out what might work better.

Charles DeLand is the Calgary-based associate director, research at the C.D. Howe Institute.

Published in the Globe and Mail

Authors